1 Henry Charles Carey and Nineteenth-Century America
Despite his theoretical and political influence on his contemporaries, Henry Charles Carey has been widely forgotten in American intellectual history. Nonetheless, his social science, conceived as a reaction to crucial economic transformations, can still be relevant in thinking the relationship between nation, society and the State on the eve of the Civil War, when the political definition of that relationship would have proved to be crucial. By “articulating in abstract form the large-scale American relations,”1 as Karl Marx, pointed out, by giving an intellectual and scientific shape to the “free labor ideology” of the Republican Party,2 to American nationalism, exceptionalism and protectionism, Carey’s works stand as significant examples of American thought within a phase of constituent transition. The aim of this paper is then to interpret Carey’s protectionism, nationalism and social science as rooted in the core of the capitalist transformation of American economy and society.
Son of Matthew Carey, an Irish political exile, Henry Charles was born in Philadelphia in 1793. In 1835, he retired from the family publishing enterprise to focus on writing on economic subjects.3 His volumes, pamphlets and articles, especially those published between the 1840s and the 1860s, made him the most widely read economist of the country, the first American economist to be translated abroad and the leading advocate for protective tariffs, making him known as “the Ajax of Protection.” A former member of the Whig Party, he actively participated in the construction of the Republican Party in Pennsylvania. He regularly wrote for the Pennsylvanian North American and United States Gazette, he founded the protectionist paper The Plough, the Loom, and the Anvil in 1845 and he was, between 1849 and 1857, the main economic editor of Horace Greeley’s New York Daily Tribune, the most influential newspaper before the Civil War, writing several unsigned articles on protection. Although he always refused to hold elected offices, he was always strongly engaged in politics. In 1856 he was a delegate to the Republican convention in Philadelphia, where he received three votes as vice-presidential candidate, and actively participated in the Frémont campaign. In 1860, during the Chicago presidential convention that nominated Abraham Lincoln, Carey imposed, through the Pennsylvanian delegation, a protective paragraph in the party platform. He had a long correspondence with Lincoln4 after his election, both on economic issues and on cabinet appointments, particularly regarding the Secretary of Treasury. Carey refused to endorse the protectionist, but allegedly corrupt, Simon Cameron, instead favoring the moderate free-trader Salmon Chase, who repeatedly asked for Carey’s advice and hired his student William Elder.5 Moreover, Carey’s contribution was crucial in drafting the Republican Tariff approved in 1861, since Justin Morrill, the main sponsor of the bill, was himself his student and political interlocutor. Carey died in 1879 at eighty-five, thus having witnessed one of the most critical periods in the history of the United States, crucial for their growth as a nation, as a capitalist market and as a State.6 As we will see, witnessing this transformation was crucial for his thought.
Since Carey’s death, only four monographic works have been devoted to Carey: Abraham Kaplan in 1931 and Rodney Morrison in 19867 both emphasize his contribution to the history of economic thought; George Smith, in 1951, reconstructs Carey’s intellectual path as highly influenced by the deepening of the sectional crisis;8 and Arnold Green, again in 1951, properly reads Carey as the first American social scientist.9 Green’s interesting hypothesis is that, while being indebted to French social thinkers like Fourier and Comte, Carey deeply influenced Durkheim, who read and quoted his Principles of Social Science.10 Partial historical accounts of Carey’s thought have been provided by historians of American economic thought,11 of American commercial policy,12 of the Republican Party during the Civil War13 and by economists.14 However, five studies on nineteenth-century America are particularly relevant in understanding Carey’s protectionism and social science. Foner’s 1970 seminal study of Republican thought reads Carey’s theory within the wider intellectual movement that shaped the 1850s free-labor ideology, highlighting Carey’s protectionism as a measure to favor the diversification of regional markets and to build a society based on small-scale production and local communities, in which the interests of capitalists and workers would have been in perfect harmony.15 Here can be traced a clear link between Carey’s harmony of interests and Lincoln’s idea of free labor. In Daniel Howe’s monograph on the Whig Party, Carey’s social science is studied as a perfect example of the Whig progressive, optimistic and capitalist vision of American development.16 Carey’s theory is also taken into account in Ross’ reconstruction of The Origins of American Social Science (1991) as an expansive version of American exceptionalism17 and as an optimistic interpretation of classical political economy, grounded in the difference of the American nation. Nicholas and Peter Onuf’s Nations, Markets and War (2006) frames Carey as the economist who, more than others, played a critical role in fostering a national sentiment in the years before the Civil War, providing the North with the conception of the nation as a moral union. In this respect, Carey’s vision of society is simultaneously his vision of the nation: a nation of local communities, homes and neighborhoods, strongly bonded by economic development.18 Distinct from Ross, they refuse to understand Carey’s nationalism as exceptionalism, claiming that he considers the United States, not an exceptional nation, but instead the country in which the laws of nature are respected. As we will see, both Ross and the Onufs are partially correct: this paper will argue that Carey’s theory is an attempt to scientifically reinterpret American exceptionalism by linking it to a natural social order. Finally, Heather Richardson’s study of Republican economic policies during the Civil War recognizes Carey, together with Francis Wayland, as the major intellectual source for the party, describing him as “the most broadly influential economist before the Civil War.”19
Drawing mainly on primary sources, but taking into account the available historiography, this paper proposes a new understanding of Carey’s nationalism as grounded in his social science and of his protectionism as the keystone of the relationship between State, nation and society. First, I argue that his nationalism and exceptionalism originated in his conception of the natural and harmonic order of American society: the social science defines his idea of the nation, its exceptional character and its universal mission. Second, I try to outline the fundamental elements of Carey’s conception of American society, particularly its progressive, harmonic and ordered character. Then, I explain how his protectionism was conceived as the necessary condition of this order, as a political measure to defend the American exception from its crises, from social conflict and from a turbulent economic change. Finally, I conclude that, through protection, Carey developed a conception of the State as the guarantee, within the capitalist transition, of societary order, of the American exception and of the American nation. To do so, I take into account Carey’s most relevant works, particularly the Principles of Political Economy (1837–1840), The Past, the Present, and the Future (1848), The Harmony of Interests (1851), The Slave Trade (1853), and the three volumes of the Principles of Social Science (1858–1860).20
3 The Order of the American Exception: Progress, Society and the Harmony of Interests
First, the American order is one of progress, of growing production and wealth: the history of the American people is a process of growing emancipation from need. The first man, “the Robinson Crusoe of his day,”30 is depicted as engaged in a fight against nature to elevate himself through work: “the desire of improving his condition impels man to desire the aid and co-operation of his fellow men.”31 Reversing Malthus’ principle of population32 and Ricardo’s principle of diminishing returns,33 in Carey’s perspective improvement is possible because men always begin with the poorer soils, the easiest to be immediately cultivated, and only after having invented instruments through cooperation with other men, they can pass to the better soils, those initially covered by trees they cannot fell and by swamps they cannot drain. Social cooperation is crucial to development, since it increases production by facilitating the cultivation of new and better lands and by improving the quality of already cultivated lands through machinery. Cooperation guarantees a growing productivity of labor through the increase of instrumental capital.
His family has increased, and he has obtained the important advantage of combination of exertion. Things that were needed to be done to render his land more rapidly productive, but which were to one man impracticable, become simple and easy when now attempted by himself and his half dozen sons, each of whom obtains far more food than he alone could at first command, and in return for far less severe exertion.34
With men always moving to cultivate better soils and with cooperation breeding production, against the “Ricardo-Malthusian doctrine” which makes man “the victim of a sad necessity,”35 Carey can assume increasing marginal returns and a principle of cooperation (as a reversed principle of population) as the axioms of his economic doctrine:36 he can assume an American theology of prosperity against the British theology of scarcity. Believing in God’s benign providence, Carey can depict the American economic order as one of indefinite and boundless growth.37 The American science of economics should therefore be a complete reversal of classical political economy, aiming at the same level of universality,38 and therefore a reversal of its political consequence: “the British system of free-trade, whose tendency is the production of discord among men and nations.”39
The American exception is instead an order of concord and its progressive growth benefits all members of society: the American order is a system of harmonies. Once again, while Ricardo and Malthus have to assume conflicting interests among the various social classes and an increasing contrast with the development of capitalist accumulation, Carey postulates a metaphysic harmony among all social interests. The social mechanism of the harmony derives from a dynamic of values. Carey’s main assumption is that the process of growth is due to an unlimited increase in labour’s productivity, a constant decline in the quantity of labour required to produce the same amount of goods, and therefore to reproduce the same amount of instrumental capital. Thus, according to Carey’s theory of labour-value as centered on the cost of reproduction,40 capital tends to lose value as compared to labour.41 Capital can therefore demand a constantly diminishing proportion of the product of labour. With the progress of development, then, workers gain control of increasing shares of the product, seeing their wages constantly rising because of a structural scarcity of labor’s supply and because of the competition among capitalists for the purchase of labor.42 The amount of the overall increase of wealth is nonetheless such that capital, while losing proportionally shares of the product, still increases in its amount, being at the same time assured about the workers’ docility. In the end, this growth of the labourer’s share of the product allows him to accumulate wealth and, in some years, to become himself a small capitalist by accessing property of land or of machinery. Workers themselves, through rising wages, are thus the agents of the accumulation of capital.
With the growth of population and wealth there is produced a constantly increasing demand for labour; and its increased productiveness, and the consequently increased facility of accumulating wealth are followed necessarily and certainly by an increase of the labourer’s proportion. His wages rise, and the proportion of the capitalists falls, yet now the latter accumulates fortune more rapidly than ever, and thus his interest and that of the labourer are in perfect harmony with each other.43
Carey’s theory of distribution goes further than claiming the harmony of interests between social classes. It directly tries to deny the existence of social classes, by accepting the distinction between capital and labor only as a temporary one, since today’s worker will be tomorrow’s capitalist.44 Thus, Carey’s harmonism can be better described as a monism: there is harmony since there is only one interest, that of capital, conceived merely as an instrument of production. Carey wants to demonstrate that in the American exceptional order there is no such thing as a permanent class of wageworkers. By describing the necessary social rise of the workers to ownership, Carey shows how private property is the very goal of the harmony of interests. The subject of his social science is a community of male individuals “possessing each his own land, and his own house, upon which he concentrates his exertion for his own improvement; and his own wife, and his own children.”45 Through ownership, individuals become self-sufficient, thus capable of economic and political self-government, thus deserving freedom. Wageworkers are not actually free, but they can become so by accessing property. The mission of America consists of this path of social elevation for those deserving it.46 The opportunities offered by American society nevertheless imply work as a duty: “the time seems to be at hand when every man must work, if he would maintain his position in society.”47 As Lincoln would after him, Carey depicts a «race of life»,48 where individuals can accumulate wealth and they can become free, but they must show their willingness to work for production: “the laws of nature require that if man would improve his condition he must work.”49 Carey, then, is still strongly influenced by the eighteenth-century and republican conception of British freedom as independence.50 Economic autonomy and property are considered the necessary conditions for freedom and the wage relationship is legitimate only if temporary and only as a means of social rise. In this respect, Carey, along with Lincoln and the Republican ideology of free labor, stands before the “transvaluation” of labor which legitimized wage labor as free in itself.51 The social rise of the labourer, making individual self-government possible, becomes the road to collective self-rule as well.52 Carey’s harmony of interests as a social order, being the material condition and the limit of American freedom, is thus the material constitution of American democracy, and therefore the necessary condition of the American exception.
This progressive and harmonic order is regulated by two mechanistic principles. The principle of concentration is what makes division of labor and social cooperation possible, allowing the diversification of production and market. Carey’s principle of concentration implies the vision of a proto-capitalist economy, a society of small and self-sufficient communities, each with a diversified internal market and a diversified production. Concentration is then the shape of social relationships in Carey’s vision of the American order, a dynamic principle, which brings a constantly increasing intensification of social interactions and of the “power of association”: concentration is what creates society. Association is the process of producing and constantly reproducing society through labour.53
Through the harmony of interests and his theory of development, then, Carey builds a theory of social order, or, more precisely, a theory of American society as an order,54 in which individuals can be free and progress can be realized only through hard work. Society, with its necessary laws of gravitation bonding individuals to each other, stands as the condition of their existence and of their freedom.55 The American man becomes a “societary man”56 and the American freedom becomes a societary freedom. Only within the order of society and after a subjugation to it, can individuals exist and be free.57 The fundamental conclusion of Carey’s social science is that in the American exceptional order, social conflict must be avoided, since it would be inconsistent with the natural functioning of the societary system. Carey’s point is that only capitalist accumulation can guarantee freedom and improvement for the (male) worker, but, in his science, this principle of social order becomes also a nationalist principle. Since the order of harmony and progress makes the United States exceptional, Carey’s theory, by describing and prescribing this order, stands as a social science of the American nation, a science of the material conditions of its legitimacy and persistence. In Carey’s perspective, protective tariffs are essential to maintain and defend this social order and thus the American nation. The social science of the nation implies protection.
5 Conclusion: Capitalist Transition and the Crises of the American Exception
Between the 1820s and the Civil War, a process of productive transition changed the American economy, transforming the United States from a horizontal country of side-by-side self-sufficient local communities and regional markets, into a country vertically integrated on the national level.74 The proto-capitalist and agricultural production for subsistence entered in a growing tension with the production for the market.75 The development of transportation and the expansion of markets were narrowing the Atlantic space, thus making the United States more vulnerable and dependent on international trade.76 The economic development was deepening the sectional division and the fracture in the national union between a North-West damaged by international trade and a South vitally leaning on it.77 The growth of manufactures and the commercialization of agriculture were contesting the economic system based on small farms, eroding the self-sufficiency of farmers and artisans, making them workers dependent upon wages:78 the household was declining as the fundamental center of production.79 The economic transformation was building a permanent class of wageworkers, particularly in cities like New York, Philadelphia, Boston and Baltimore,80 paving the way to the formation of a working class increasingly conscious of its condition and willing to fight to improve it.81 The territorial expansion of the nation and the unrestrained westward migration were accelerating the end of the frontier and the closing of the American space. In other words, the preindustrial world of the self-sufficient farmers and of the independent mechanic was fading into obscurity.82 Carey’s proto-capitalist conception of American society as a harmonic order of small producers was being contested by economic development. The material conditions of the American exception were falling apart.
All together, these processes represented the culmination of the transition of American economy towards a capitalist mode of production. However, capitalist development, far from leading workers towards a growing power over the product of labour, as Carey thought, resulted in a complete loss of control over the conditions of labour. The market revolution was deskilling and proletarianizing the independent labourers, increasing the disparities between journeymen and masters, requiring an increasing quantity of capital to set up one’s own business, thus making it increasingly difficult to abandon the condition of wage labourer.83 As Marx pointed out in criticizing Carey’s harmony of interests, the increasing productivity of labour in no way could benefit the labourer, but only capital.
The growth of the productive forces expresses itself in a continuous decline of the part of capital consisting of labour compared with that laid out in advances, machinery, etc. Carey’s entire bad joke … rests on his transformation of the labour time into labour time belonging to the worker, whereas this time belongs in fact to capital, and an even smaller portion of it remains for the worker in proportion to the growth of the productive forces of labour.84
Capitalist development, contrary to Carey’s expectations, was not allowing the labourer to buy the machines of production but it was instead destroying his independence, opening “an infinite gap between his labour and the conditions of its employment.”85
In America, as long as the worker there still appropriates a part of his surplus labour for himself, he may accumulate enough to become e.g. a farmer etc. (although that too is already coming to a halt now). In places where wage labour in America can still get somewhere rapidly, this happens through the reproduction of earlier modes of production and property on the foundation of capital (e. g. the independent peasantry.86
Marx understood that Carey’s harmonic order was only possible in a proto-capitalist economy, only at the beginning of capitalist development, only in a moment of persisting coexistence between the capitalist mode of production and its predecessors. Thus, because of the capitalist transition, the American dream of a harmony of interests was being disrupted.
Carey reacted to this process, trying to understand how to keep society ordered and how to preserve the American exception within this tumultuous transition. His solution was, through protection, the definitive construction of the American State, begun with the Revolution but still in process: his solution was to build the State as the agent of the capitalist transition,87 and he could conceive this solution because he could see a State already implementing economic development.88 Despite his repeated invocation of the spontaneous character of development as a result of providential design, Carey revealed, in the end, a deep distrust of society, which could develop by itself, but could not be ordered and safe without the State. Only by charging the State with the control of this transition, capitalist development could be kept on an ordered path and the exception could be saved. Only by creating a national integrated and differentiated market, by isolating it from international trade and from the shrinking of the Atlantic space, by concentrating the economic resources in the East, thus keeping open the American frontier and controlling the mobility of the workforce, the tumultuous transition could be politically governed. Above all, Carey’s State had to build and maintain, in the capitalist transition, the harmony of interests between capital and labor, the main condition of the American order as exceptional. This meant vesting the State with the herculean task of favoring capitalist accumulation while guaranteeing the improvement of the labourer’s condition, or, more precisely, the task of favoring capitalist accumulation while neutralizing social conflict. Carey’s State had to become the political actor enforcing peace between capital and labor. Carey’s utopia was therefore the construction, through the State, of a capitalism without class struggle.
Carey understood that the proto-capitalist order of farmers, local communities and regional markets was being transformed, but, to him, this transformation meant a structural crisis of the material conditions of the American exception. From his point of view, the American mission could not be realized without an economy making the social mobility of the laborer and the harmonic growth of wealth possible. It could not be realized in a heavily industrial society, with large-scale corporations and a permanent working-class. Carey thought that only the State could maintain capitalist development in the path of an ordered and harmonic society and that only the State could save the American exception from the European specters of poverty and class conflict. What Carey did not understand was that such a task was too challenging, even for what was to become the most powerful State in the world. Moreover, he did not understand that after the economic transformation of the first half of nineteenth-century, capitalist accumulation and the harmony of interests could not coexist anymore in the United States and that class conflict was a price that capitalism would have been forced to pay by the restlessness of the American working class. Finally, he did not understand that protection, by favoring the growing of large-scale industries, would have deepened, instead of softened, the crisis of his social order, and that class conflict would have risen in the Reconstruction also as a result of the industrial concentration brought by protection.89
Carey’s social science should therefore be understood as a reaction to the transition of the American economy to industrial capitalism, a transition contesting the material foundations of his conception of the American exceptional order, thus compromising the legitimacy of the American nation. With his social science depicting the order of harmony and the ways to preserve it, Carey tried to offer a new source of legitimacy to the American nation, thinking the State, through protection, as its necessary condition: a scientific theory of the persistence of the American order at the eve of its breakdown. Carey’s social science is therefore a science of the American nation as exceptional because of its social order, but a nation and a social order produced, maintained and made exceptional only by the State and within the State. Denying the idea of America as a “nation without State,” Carey’s protectionism conceives, on the eve of the Civil War, the United States as a “nation because of the State.” Carey’s social science of the nation thus marks a reinterpretation of American nationalism centered on protection as the means of maintaining the harmonic order of society as the material conditions of the American exception: a reinterpretation conceiving the State as the guarantee of society and of the nation.
References
——. Henry C. Carey Papers, Edward Carey Gardiner Collection, Historical Society of Pennsylvania.
——. Miscellaneous Works of Henry C. Carey, Kislak Center for Special Collections, Manuscripts and Rare Books, University of Pennsylvania.
Anderson, Bendict. Imagined Communities. Reflections on the Origin and Spread of Nationalism. London: Verso, 1983.
Baritono, Raffaella. “Uno Stato a ‘bassa intensità’? L'esperienza storica statunitense,” in Lo Stato globale, eds. Raffaella Gherardi, Maurizio Ricciardi. Bologna: CLUEB, 2009, 81–110.
Battistini, Matteo. “A National Blessing: debito e credito pubblico nella fondazione atlantica degli Stati Uniti d’America,” Scienza & Politica, 48 (2013): 13–31.
Blackburn, Robin. Marx and Lincoln: An Unfinished Revolution. London-New York: Verso, 2011.
Bonazzi, Tiziano. “La guerra civile americana e la nazione universale,” in La guerra civile americana vista dall’Europa, ed. Tiziano Bonazzi, Carlo Galli. Bologna: Il Mulino, 2004, 463–502.
——. Abraham Lincoln. Un dramma americano. Bologna: Il Mulino, 2011.
Carey, Henry Charles. Principles of Political Economy. Philadelphia: Carey, Lea & Blanchard, 3 vols., 1837–1840.
——. The Past, the Present, and the Future. Philadelphia: Carey & Hart, 1848.
——. The Harmony of Interests, Agricultural, Manufacturing, and Commercial. New York: Myron Finch, 1856 [1st ed. 1851].
——. The Slave Trade, Domestic and Foreign. Philadelphia: Hart, 1853.
——. Principles of Social Science. Philadelphia: Lippincott & Co., 3 vols., 1858–1860.
Cohen, I. Bernard. The Natural Sciences and the Social Sciences: some critical and historical perspectives. Boston: Boston Studies in the Philosophy of Science, 1993.
Conkin, Paul T. Prophets of Prosperity: America’s First Political Economists. Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1980.
Dorfman, Joseph. The Economic Mind in American Civilization. New York: Kelley, 5 vols., 1946.
Durkheim, Émile. The Division of Labour in Society. New York: Free Press, 1964.
Eiselen, Malcolm R. The Rise of Pennsylvania Protectionism. Philadelphia: The University of Philadelphia Press, 1932.
Foner, Eric. Free Soil, Free Labor, Free Men. The Ideology of the Republican Party before the Civil War. New York: Oxford University Press, 1995 [1st ed. 1970].
——. Reconstruction. America’s Unfinished Revolution, 1863–1877. New York: Harper Perennial, 2014 [1st ed. 1988].
——. The Story of American Freedom. New York: Norton, 1998.
——. The Fiery Trial. Abraham Lincoln and American Slavery. New York: Norton, 2010.
Genovese, Eugene D. The Political Economy of Slavery: Studies in the Economy and Society of the Slave South. Middletown, CT: Wesleyan University Press, 1989 [1st ed. 1961].
Green, Arnold W. Henry Charles Carey. Nineteenth-Century Sociologist. Philadelphia: Pennsylvania University Press, 1951.
Greene, Jack P. The Intellectual Construction of America. Exceptionalism and Identity from 1492 to 1800. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1997.
Hofstadter, Richard. “The Tariff Issue and the Civil War,” American Historical Review, 44 (1938), 50–55.
Howe, Daniel W. The Political Culture of the American Whigs. Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, 1979.
Huston, James L. “A Political Response to Industrialism: The Republican Embrace of Protectionist Labor Doctrines,” The Journal of American History, 70 (1983), 35–57.
Kaplan, Abraham D. H. Henry Charles Carey. A Study in American Economic Thought. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1931.
Kulikoff, Allan. Abraham Lincoln and Karl Marx in Dialogue. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2018.
Laurie, Bruce. Artisans into Workers. Labor in Nineteenth-Century America. New York: Noonday Press, 1989.
Lee, Arthur M. “Henry C. Carey and the Republican Tariff,” The Pennsylvania Magazine of History and Biography, 81 (1957), 280–302.
Lincoln, Abraham. The Collected Works of Abraham Lincoln, ed. Roy Basler. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 8 vols., 1953–1955.
Luthin, Reinhard H. “Abraham Lincoln and the Tariff,” American Historical Review, 49 (1944), 609–629.
Malthus, Thomas. An Essay on the Principle of Population and Other Writings, ed. Robert J. Mayhew. London: Penguin Random House, 2015.
Mariano, Marco. L’America nell’Occidente. Storia della dottrina Monroe (1823–1963). Roma: Carocci, 2013.
Marx, Karl. Gründrisse. Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy, ed. Ben Fowkes. New York: Penguin, 1973.
Marx, Karl, Engels, Friedrich. The Civil War in the United States, ed. Andrew Zimmerman. New York: International Publishers, 2016.
Meardon, Stephen. “Henry Carey's ‘Zone Theory’ and American Sectional Conflict.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 37 (2015), 305–320.
Montgomery, David. Beyond Equality. Labor and Radical Republicans 1862–1872. Chicago: University of Illinois Press, 1981 [1st ed. 1967].
——. “The Working Classes of the Pre-Industrial American City,” Labor History, 9 (1968), 3–22.
Morrison, Rodney J. Henry C. Carey and American Economic Development. Philadelphia: Transactions of the American Philosophical Society, 1986.
Onuf, Nicholas, Onuf, Peter S. Nations, Markets and War: Modern History and the American Civil War. London-Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, 2006.
Parisi, Donatella. “Nascita e sviluppo dell’American System of Political Economy. Il pensiero economico nordamericano tra Settecento e Ottocento,” Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali, 98 (1990), 547–581.
Perelman, Michael. Marx’s Crises Theory. Scarcity, Labor and Finance. New York: Praeger, 1987.
Rabbeno, Ugo. The American Commercial Policy. New York: MacMillan, 1895.
Ricardo, David. Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, ed. Donald Winch. London: Dent & Sons, 1973.
Ricciardi, Maurizio. La società come ordine. Storia e teoria politica dei concetti sociali. Macerata: EUM, 2010.
Richardson, Heather C. The Greatest Nation on Earth. Republican Economic Policies during the Civil War. Cambride, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997.
Ron, Ariel. “Henry Carey's Rural Roots, ‘Scientific Agriculture,’ and Economic Development in the Antebellum North,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 37 (2015), 263–275.
Ross, Dorothy. The Origins of American Social Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. History of Economic Analysis. New York: Oxford University Press, 1954.
Sellers, Charles. The Market Revolution. Jacksonian America 1815–1848. New York: Oxford University Press, 1991.
Smith, George W. Henry C. Carey and American Sectional Conflict. Albuquerque: The University of New Mexico Press, 1951.
Stephanson, Anders. Manifest Destiny. American Expansionism and the Empire of Right. New York: Hill and Wang, 1996.
Taussig, Frank W. Tariff History of the United States. New York: Putnam’s Sons, 1914.
Teilhac, Ernest. Pioneers of American Economic Thought in the Nineteenth Century. New York: Russell, 1967.
Turner, John R. The Ricardian Rent Theory in Early American Economics. New York: The New York University Press, 1921.
Wiebe, Robert H. Self-Rule. A Cultural History of American Democracy. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1995.
Wilentz, Sean. Chants Democratic. New York City and the Rise of the American Working Class. New York: Oxford University Press, 2004 [1st ed. 1984].
Karl Marx, Gründrisse. Foundations of the Critique of Political Economy, ed. Ben Fowkes (New York: Penguin, 1973), 888.↩
Eric Foner, Free Soil, Free Labor, Free Men. The Ideology of the Republican Party before the Civil War, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1995, 1st ed. 1970); Eric Foner, The Fiery Trial. Abraham Lincoln and American Slavery (New York: Norton, 2010), 33–41; Tiziano Bonazzi, Abraham Lincoln. Un dramma americano, (Bologna: Il Mulino, 2011).↩
Abraham D.H. Kaplan, Henry Charles Carey. A Study in American Economic Thought (Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1931); George W. Smith, Henry C. Carey and American Sectional Conflict (Albuquerque: The University of New Mexico Press, 1951); Arnold W. Green, Henry Charles Carey. Nineteenth-Century Sociologist (Philadelphia: Pennsylvania University Press, 1951).↩
Henry C. Carey Papers, Edward Carey Gardiner Collection, Historical Society of Pennsylvania.↩
Arthur M. Lee, “Henry C. Carey and the Republican Tariff,” The Pennsylvania Magazine of History and Biography, 81 (1957), 280–302; Heather C. Richardson, The Greatest Nation on Earth. Republican Economic Policies during the Civil War, (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1997), 19–20.↩
The custom of conjugating «United States» as a singular subject became prevalent only after the Civil War, as a nationalist and ideological distortion of the English language. This paper will instead treat them as a plural entity, as they were for the most part of the nineteenth century and as Carey himself does in his writings.↩
Kaplan, Henry Charles Carey; Rodney J. Morrison, Henry C. Carey and American Economic Development (Philadelphia: Transactions of the American Philosophical Society, 1986).↩
Smith, Henry C. Carey and American Sectional Conflict.↩
Green, Henry Charles Carey.↩
Émile Durkheim, The Division of Labour in Society, (New York: Free Press, 1964), 393–394.↩
Paul T. Conkin, Prophets of Prosperity: America’s First Political Economists, (Bloomington: Indiana University Press, 1980); Joseph Dorfman, The Economic Mind in American Civilization, vol. 2, (New York: Kelley, 1946); Malcom R. Eiselen, The Rise of Pennsylvania Protectionism, (Philadelphia: The University of Philadelphia Press, 1932); Ernest Teilhac, Pioneers of American Economic Thought in the Nineteenth Century, (New York: Russell, 1967); John R. Turner, The Ricardian Rent Theory in Early American Economics, (New York: The New York University Press, 1921); Donatella Parisi, “Nascita e sviluppo dell’American System of Political Economy. Il pensiero economico nordamericano tra Settecento e Ottocento,” Rivista Internazionale di Scienze Sociali, 98 (1990), 547–581.↩
Ugo Rabbeno, The American Commercial Policy, (New York: Macmillan, 1895); Frank W. Taussig, Tariff History of the United States, (New York: Putnam’s Sons, 1914).↩
Richard Hofstadter, “The Tariff Issue and the Civil War,” American Historical Review, 44 (1938), 50–55; James L. Huston, “A Political Response to Industrialism: The Republican Embrace of Protectionist Labor Doctrines,” The Journal of American History, 70 (1983), 35–57; Reinhard H. Luthin, “Abraham Lincoln and the Tariff,” American Historical Review, 49 (1944), 609–629.↩
Stephen Meardon, “Henry Carey's ‘Zone Theory’ and American Sectional Conflict,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 37 (2015), 305–320; Michael Perelman, Marx’s Crises Theory. Scarcity, Labor and Finance (New York: Praeger, 1987); Ariel Ron, “Henry Carey's Rural Roots, ‘Scientific Agriculture,’ and Economic Development in the Antebellum North,” Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 37 (2015), 263–275.↩
Foner, Free Soil, Free Labor, Free Men, 19–20, 36–39.↩
Daniel W. Howe, The Political Culture of the American Whigs, (Chicago, The University of Chicago Press, 1979), 108–122.↩
Dorothy Ross, The Origins of American Social Science, (Cambridge-New York: Cambridge University Press, 1991), 44–48.↩
Nicholas Onuf, Peter S. Onuf, Nations, Markets and War: Modern History and the American Civil War, (London-Charlottesville: University of Virginia Press, 2006), 283–285.↩
Richardson, The Greatest Nation of the Earth, 19.↩
Henry C. Carey, Principles of Political Economy (Philadelphia: Carey, Lea & Blanchard, 1837–1840), The Past, the Present, and the Future (Philadelphia: Carey & Hart, 1848), The Harmony of Interests (New York: Myron Finch, 1856, 1st ed. 1851), The Slave Trade (Philadelphia: Hart, 1853), Principles of Social Science (Philadelphia: Lippincott & Co., 1858–1860).↩
Jack P. Greene, The Intellectual Construction of America. Exceptionalism and Identity from 1492 to 1800, (Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 1997).↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 5–6.↩
Ibid, 296.↩
Onuf, Onuf, Nations, Markets and War, 298.↩
Foner, Free Soil, Free Labor, Free Men, 11–18.↩
Carey, The Harmony of Interests, 228–229.↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 446–447↩
Carey, The Harmony of Interests, 229.↩
Benedict Anderson, Imagined Communities. Reflections on the Origin and Spread of Nationalism, (London: Verso, 1983).↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 9.↩
Carey, Principles of Political Economy, vol. 1, 339.↩
Thomas Malthus, An Essay on the Principle of Population and Other Writings, (London: Penguin Random House, 2015).↩
David Ricardo, Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, (London: Dent & Sons, 1973).↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 12.↩
Ibid, 248.↩
Ibid, 17–26, 77–93.↩
Ibid, 13–14.↩
Conkin, Prophets of Prosperity, 262.↩
Carey, The Harmony of Interests, III.↩
Morrison, Henry C. Carey and American Economic Development, 8–18.↩
Joseph A. Schumpeter, History of Economic Analysis (New York: Oxford University Press, 1954), 518.↩
Carey, Principles of Social Science, vol. 3, 235.↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 67.↩
Foner, Free Soil, Free Labor, Free Men, 20.↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 289.↩
Ibid, 214.↩
Ibid, 219.↩
Abraham Lincoln, “Message to Congress in Special Session,” July 4, 1861, in The Collected Works of Abraham Lincoln, ed. Roy Basler (New Brunswick, N. J.: Rutgers University Press, 8 vols., 1953–1955), vol. 4, 438.↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, p. 38.↩
Eric Foner, The Story of American Freedom, (New York: Norton, 1998), 7–9.↩
Ibid, 58–68.↩
Robert Wiebe, Self-Rule. A Cultural History of American Democracy, (Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1995), 39.↩
Carey, Principles of Social Science, vol. 1, 138.↩
Maurizio Ricciardi, La società come ordine. Storia e teoria politica dei concetti sociali, (Macerata: EUM, 2010), 15–53.↩
Ibid, 17–18.↩
Carey, Principles of Social Science, vol. 3, 406.↩
Ibid, vol. 3, 469–470.↩
Bernard Cohen, The Natural Sciences and the Social Sciences: some critical and historical perspectives (Boston: Boston Studies in the Philosophy of Science, 1993), 17–22.↩
Carey, The Harmony of Interests, 10–40.↩
Ibid, 41–51, 86–91, 78–86.↩
Ibid, 141–161, 161–185, 91–141.↩
Ibid, 193–217.↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 469.↩
Carey, The Harmony of Interests, 49.↩
Richardson, The Greatest Nation on Earth, 136–137.↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 470,↩
Marx to Engels, June 14, 1853, in Karl Marx, Friedrich Engels, The Civil War in the United States, ed. A. Zimmerman, (New York: International Publishers, 2016), 10.↩
Perelman, Marx’s Crises Theory.↩
Marx, Gründrisse, 885–887.↩
Carey, The Past, the Present, and the Future, 288.↩
Carey, Principles of Social Science, vol. 3, 211.↩
Ibid, vol. 3, 409.↩
Ibid, vol. 3, 414.↩
Wiebe, Self-Rule; Tiziano Bonazzi, “La guerra civile americana e la nazione universale,” in La guerra civile americana vista dall’Europa, eds. Tiziano Bonazzi, Carlo Galli (Bologna: Il Mulino, 2004), 463–502.↩
Charles Sellers, The Market Revolution. Jacksonian America 1815–1848, (New York: Oxford University Press, 1991), 3–33.↩
Marco Mariano, L’America nell’Occidente. Storia della dottrina Monroe (1823–1963), (Roma: Carocci, 2013), 83–94.↩
Eugene D. Genovese, The Political Economy of Slavery: Studies in the Economy and Society of the Slave South, (Middletown, CT: Wesleyan University Press, 1989, 1st ed. 1961).↩
Bruce Laurie, Artisans into Workers. Labor in Nineteenth-Century America, (New York: Noonday Press, 1989), 16.↩
Foner, The Story of American Freedom, 55.↩
Sean Wilentz, Chants Democratic. New York City and the Rise of the American Working Class, (New York-Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2004, 1st ed. 1984).↩
David Montgomery, Beyond Equality. Labor and Radical Republicans 1862–1872, (Chicago: University of Illinois Press, 1981, 1st ed. 1967), 3–44.↩
Laurie, Artisans into Workers, 46.↩
Sellers, The Market Revolution, 25–26.↩
Marx, Gründrisse, 580.↩
Ibid, 581.↩
Ibid, 579.↩
Matteo Battistini, “A National Blessing: debito e credito pubblico nella fondazione atlantica degli Stati Uniti d’America,” Scienza & Politica, 48 (2013), 13–31.↩
Raffaella Baritono, Uno Stato a “bassa intensità”? L’esperienza storica statunitense, in Lo Stato globale, eds. Raffaella Gherardi, Maurizio Ricciardi (Bologna: CLUEB, 2009), 81–110.↩
Eric Foner, Reconstruction. America’s Unfinished Revolution, 1863–1877, (New York: Harper Perennial, 2014, 1st ed. 1988).↩